Angry about inequality? Don’t blame the rich.
By James Q. Wilson
There is no doubt that incomes are unequal in the United States — far more so
than in most European nations. This fact is part of the impulse behind the
Occupy Wall Street movement, whose members claim to represent the 99 percent
of us against the wealthiest 1 percent. It has also sparked a major debate in
the Republican presidential race, where former Massachusetts governor Mitt
Romney has come under
fire for his tax rates and his career as the head of a private-equity
firm.
And economic
disparity was the recurring theme of President Obama’s State of the Union
address on Tuesday. “We can either settle for a country where a shrinking
number of people do really well, while a growing number of Americans barely get
by,” the president warned, “or we can restore an economy where everyone gets a
fair shot and everyone does their fair share.”
But the mere existence of income inequality tells us little about what, if
anything, should be done about it. First, we must answer some key questions. Who
constitutes the prosperous and the poor? Why has inequality increased? Does an
unequal income distribution deny poor people the chance to buy what they want?
And perhaps most important: How do Americans feel about inequality?
To answer these questions, it is not enough to take a snapshot of our
incomes; we must instead have a motion picture of them and of how people move in
and out of various income groups over time.
The “rich” in America are not a monolithic, unchanging class. A study by
Thomas A. Garrett, economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, found
that less than half of people in the top 1 percent in 1996 were still there in
2005. Such mobility is hardly surprising: A business school student, for
instance, may have little money and high debts, but nine years later he or she
could be earning a big Wall Street salary and bonus.
Mobility is not limited to the top-earning households. A study by
economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis found that nearly half
of the families in the lowest fifth of income earners in 2001 had moved up
within six years. Over the same period, more than a third of those in the
highest fifth of income-earners had moved down. Certainly, there are people such
as Warren Buffett and Bill Gates who are ensconced in the top tier, but far more
common are people who are rich for short periods.
And who are the rich? Affluent people, compared with poor ones, tend to have
greater education and spouses who work full time. The past three decades have
seen significant increases in real earnings for people with advanced degrees.
The Bureau of Labor Statistics found that between 1979 and 2010, hourly wages for men and women with
at least a college degree rose by 33 percent and 20 percent, respectively,
while they fell for all people with less than a high school diploma — by 9
percent for women and 31 percent for men.
Also, households with two earners have seen their incomes rise. This trend is
driven in part by women’s increasing workforce participation, which doubled from
1950 to 2005 and which began to place women in well-paid jobs by the early
1980s.
We could reduce income inequality by trying to curtail the financial returns
of education and the number of women in the workforce — but who would want to do
that?
The real income problem in this country is not a question of who is rich, but
rather of who is poor. Among the bottom fifth of income earners, many people,
especially men, stay there their whole lives. Low education and unwed motherhood
only exacerbate poverty, which is particularly acute among racial minorities.
Brookings Institution economist Scott Winshiphas
argued that two-thirds of black children in America experience a level of
poverty that only 6 percent of white children will ever see, calling it a
“national tragedy.”
Making the poor more economically mobile has nothing to do with taxing the
rich and everything to do with finding and implementing ways to encourage
parental marriage, teach the poor marketable skills and induce them to join the
legitimate workforce. It is easy to suppose that raising taxes on the rich would
provide more money to help the poor. But the problem facing the poor is not too
little money, but too few skills and opportunities to advance themselves.
Income inequality has increased in this country and in practically every
European nation in recent decades. The best measure of that change is the Gini
index, named after the Italian statistician Corrado Gini, who designed it in
1912. The index values vary between zero, when everyone has exactly the same
income, and 1, when one person has all of the income and everybody else has
none. In mid-1970s America, the index was 0.316, but it had reached 0.378 by the
late 2000s. One of the few nations to see its Gini value fall was Greece, which
went from 0.413 in the 1970s to 0.307 in the late 2000s. So Greece seems to be
reducing income inequality — but with little to buy, riots
in the streets and economic opportunity largely limited to those partaking
in corruption, the nation is hardly a model for anyone’s economy.
Poverty in America is certainly a serious problem, but the plight of the poor
has been moderated by advances in the economy. Between 1970 and 2010, the net
worth of American households more than doubled, as did the number of television
sets and air-conditioning units per home. In his book “The
Poverty of the Poverty Rate,” Nicholas Eberstadt shows that over the past 30
or so years, the percentage of low-income children in the United States who are
underweight has gone down, the share of low-income households lacking complete
plumbing facilities has declined, and the area of their homes adequately heated
has gone up. The fraction of poor households with a telephone, a television set
and a clothes dryer has risen sharply.
In other words, the country has become more prosperous, as measured not by
income but by consumption: In constant dollars, consumption by people in the
lowest quintile rose by more than 40 percent over the past four decades.
Income as measured by the federal government is not a reliable indicator of
well-being, but consumption is. Though poverty is a problem, it has become less
of one.
Historically, Americans have had an unusual attitude toward income
inequality. In 1985, political scientists Sidney Verba and Gary Orren published
a book that compared how liberals in Sweden and in the United States viewed such
inequality. By four or five to one, the Swedish liberals were more likely than
the American ones to believe that it was important to give workers equal pay.
The Swedes were three times more likely than the Americans to favor putting a
top limit on incomes. (The Swedes get a lot of what they want: Their Gini index
is 0.259, much lower than America’s.)
Sweden has maintained a low Gini index in part by having more progressive tax
rates. If Americans wanted to follow the Swedish example, they could. But what
is the morally fair way to determine tax rates — other than taxing everyone at
the same rate? The case for progressive tax rates is far from settled; just read
Kip Hagopian’s recent
essay in Policy Review, which makes a powerful argument against progressive
taxation because it fails to take into account aptitude and work effort.
American views about inequality have not changed much in the past
quarter-century. In their 2009 book “Class
War? What Americans Really Think About Economic Inequality,” political
scientists Benjamin Page and Lawrence Jacobs report that big majorities,
including poor people, agree that “it is ‘still possible’ to start out poor in
this country, work hard, and become rich,” and reject the view that it is the
government’s job to narrow the income gap. More recently, a
December Gallup poll showed that 52 percent of Americans say inequality is
“an acceptable part” of the nation’s economic system, compared with 45 percent
who deemed it a “problem that needs to be fixed.” Similarly, 82 percent said economic
growth is “extremely important” or “very important,” compared with 46
percent saying that reducing the gap between rich and poor is extremely or very
important.
Suppose we tax the rich more heavily — who would get the money, and for what
goals?
Reducing poverty, rather than inequality, is also a difficult task, but at
least the end is clearer. One new strategy for helping the poor improve their
condition is known as the
“social impact bond,” which is being tested in Britain and has been endorsed
by the Obama administration. Under this approach, private investors, including
foundations, put up money to pay for a program or initiative to help low-income
people get jobs, stay out of prison or remain in school, for example. A
government agency evaluates the results. If the program is succeeding, the
agency reimburses the investors; if not, they get no government money.
As Harvard economist Jeffrey Liebman has
pointed out, for this system to work there must be careful measures of
success and a reasonable chance for investors to make a profit. Massachusetts is
ready to try such an effort. It may not be easy for the social impact bond model
to work consistently, but it offers one big benefit: Instead of carping about
who is rich, we would be trying to help people who are poor.
outlook@washpost.com
James Q. Wilson, a former professor at Harvard University and UCLA, is
the Ronald Reagan professor of public policy at Pepperdine University. He is the
author of “American
Politics, Then & Now,” “The
Marriage Problem: How Our Culture Has Weakened Families” and “The
Moral Sense.”
http://www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/angry-about-inequality-dont-blame-the-rich/2012/01/03/gIQA9S2fTQ_print.html
No comments:
Post a Comment